Banzhaf power index







Computer model of the Banzhaf power index from the Wolfram Demonstrations Project


The Banzhaf power index, named after John F. Banzhaf III (originally invented by Lionel Penrose in 1946 and sometimes called Penrose–Banzhaf index; also known as the Banzhaf–Coleman index after James Samuel Coleman), is a power index defined by the probability of changing an outcome of a vote where voting rights are not necessarily equally divided among the voters or shareholders.


To calculate the power of a voter using the Banzhaf index, list all the winning coalitions, then count the critical voters. A critical voter is a voter who, if he changed his vote from yes to no, would cause the measure to fail. A voter's power is measured as the fraction of all swing votes that he could cast. There are some algorithms for calculating the power index, e.g., dynamic programming techniques, enumeration methods and Monte Carlo methods.[1]




Contents






  • 1 Examples


    • 1.1 Voting game


      • 1.1.1 Simple voting game


      • 1.1.2 U.S. Electoral College




    • 1.2 Cartel game




  • 2 History


  • 3 See also


  • 4 Notes


  • 5 References


    • 5.1 Footnotes


    • 5.2 Bibliography




  • 6 External links





Examples



Voting game



Simple voting game


A simple voting game, taken from Game Theory and Strategy by Philip D. Straffin:[2]


[6; 4, 3, 2, 1]


The numbers in the brackets mean a measure requires 6 votes to pass, and voter A can cast four votes, B three votes, C two, and D one. The winning groups, with underlined swing voters, are as follows:


AB, AC, ABC, ABD, ACD, BCD, ABCD


There are 12 total swing votes, so by the Banzhaf index, power is divided thus:


A = 5/12, B = 3/12, C = 3/12, D = 1/12



U.S. Electoral College


Consider the United States Electoral College. Each state has more or less power than the next state. There are a total of 538 electoral votes. A majority vote is considered 270 votes. The Banzhaf power index would be a mathematical representation of how likely a single state would be able to swing the vote. A state such as California, which is allocated 55 electoral votes, would be more likely to swing the vote than a state such as Montana, which has 3 electoral votes.


Assume the United States is having a presidential election between a Republican (R) and a Democrat (D). For simplicity, suppose that only three states are participating: California (55 electoral votes), Texas (38 electoral votes), and New York (29 electoral votes).


The possible outcomes of the election are:











































































California (55)
Texas (38)
New York (29)
R votes
D votes
States that could swing the vote
R
R
R
122
0
none
R
R
D
93
29
California (D would win 84–38), Texas (D would win 67–55)
R
D
R
84
38
California (D would win 93–29), New York (D would win 67–55)
R
D
D
55
67
Texas (R would win 93–29), New York (R would win 84–38)
D
R
R
67
55
Texas (D would win 93–29), New York (D would win 84–38)
D
R
D
38
84
California (R would win 93–29), New York (R would win 67–55)
D
D
R
29
93
California (R would win 84–38), Texas (R would win 67–55)
D
D
D
0
122
none

The Banzhaf power index of a state is the proportion of the possible outcomes in which that state could swing the election. In this example, all three states have the same index: 4/12 or 1/3.


However, if New York is replaced by Georgia, with only 16 electoral votes, the situation changes dramatically.











































































California (55)
Texas (38)
Georgia (16)
R votes
D votes
States that could swing the vote
R
R
R
109
0
California (D would win 55–54)
R
R
D
93
16
California (D would win 71–38)
R
D
R
71
38
California (D would win 93–16)
R
D
D
55
54
California (D would win 109–0)
D
R
R
54
55
California (R would win 109–0)
D
R
D
38
71
California (R would win 93–16)
D
D
R
16
93
California (R would win 71–38)
D
D
D
0
109
California (R would win 55–54)

In this example, the Banzhaf index gives California 1 and the other states 0, since California alone has more than half the votes.



Cartel game


Five companies (A, B, C, D, E) sign an agreement for the creation of a monopoly. The size of the market is X = 54 million units per year (e.g. petroleum barrels) for a monopoly. The maximum production capacity of these companies is A = 44, B = 32, C = 20, D = 8 and E = 4 million units per year. Therefore, there is a set of coalitions able to provide the 54 million units necessary for the monopoly, and a set of coalitions unable to provide that number. In each of the sufficient coalitions one may have necessary members (for the coalition to provide the required production) and unnecessary members (underlined in the table below). Even when one of these unnecessary members goes out of the sufficient coalition that coalition is able to provide the required production. However, when one necessary member leaves, the sufficient coalition becomes insufficient. The monopoly's profit to be distributed among the coalition's members is 100 million dollars per year.











Sufficient coalitions
ABCDE, ABCD, ABCE, ABDE, ACDE, ABC, ABD, ABE, ACD, ACE, BCDE, BCD, BCE, ADE, AB and AC
Insufficient coalitions CDE, BDE, AD, AE, BC, BD, BE, CD, CE, DE, A, B, C, D and E

The Penrose–Banzhaf index may be applied to the calculation of the Shapley value, which provides a basis for a distribution of the profit for each player in the game in proportion to the number of sufficient coalitions in which that player is necessary. The player A is necessary for 10 of the 16 sufficient coalitions, B is necessary for 6, C also for 6, D for 2 and E for 2. Therefore, A is necessary in 38.5% of the total cases (26 = 10 + 6 + 6 + 2 + 2, so 10/26 = 0.385), B in 23.1%, C in 23.1%, D in 7.7% and E in 7.7% (these are the Banzhaf indexes for each company). The distribution of the 100 millions of monopoly profits under the Shapley value's criterion has to follow those proportions.



History


What is known today as the Banzhaf power index was originally introduced by Lionel Penrose in 1946[3] and went largely forgotten.[4] It was reinvented by John F. Banzhaf III in 1965,[5] but it had to be reinvented once more by James Samuel Coleman in 1971[6] before it became part of the mainstream literature.


Banzhaf wanted to prove objectively that the Nassau County board's voting system was unfair. As given in Game Theory and Strategy, votes were allocated as follows:[2]



  • Hempstead #1: 9

  • Hempstead #2: 9

  • North Hempstead: 7

  • Oyster Bay: 3

  • Glen Cove: 1

  • Long Beach: 1


This is 30 total votes, and a simple majority of 16 votes was required for a measure to pass.[a]


In Banzhaf's notation, [Hempstead #1, Hempstead #2, North Hempstead, Oyster Bay, Glen Cove, Long Beach] are A-F in [16; 9, 9, 7, 3, 1, 1]


There are 32 winning coalitions, and 48 swing votes:


AB AC BC ABC ABD ABE ABF ACD ACE ACF BCD BCE BCF ABCD ABCE ABCF ABDE ABDF ABEF ACDE ACDF ACEF BCDE BCDF BCEF ABCDE ABCDF ABCEF ABDEF ACDEF BCDEF ABCDEF


The Banzhaf index gives these values:



  • Hempstead #1 = 16/48

  • Hempstead #2 = 16/48

  • North Hempstead = 16/48

  • Oyster Bay = 0/48

  • Glen Cove = 0/48

  • Long Beach = 0/48


Banzhaf argued that a voting arrangement that gives 0% of the power to 16% of the population is unfair.[b]


Today,[when?] the Banzhaf power index is an accepted way to measure voting power, along with the alternative Shapley–Shubik power index. Both measures have been applied to the analysis of voting in the Council of the European Union.[7]


However, Banzhaf's analysis has been critiqued as treating votes like coin-flips, and an empirical model of voting rather than a random voting model as used by Banzhaf brings different results.[8]



See also




  • Game theory

  • Penrose method

  • Penrose square root law



Notes





  1. ^ Banzhaf did not understand how voting in Nassau County actually worked. Initially 24 votes were apportioned to Hempstead, resulting in 36 total votes. Hempstead was then limited to half of the total, or 18, or 9 for each supervisor. The six eliminated votes were not voted, and the majority required to pass a measure remained at 19.


  2. ^ Many sources claim that Banzhaf sued (and won). In the original Nassau County litigation, Franklin v. Mandeville 57 Misc.2d 1072 (1968), a New York court ruled that voters in Hempstead were denied equal protection equal because while the town had a majority of the population, they did not have a majority of the weighted vote. Weighted voting would be litigated in Nassau County for the next 25 years, until it was eliminated.




References



Footnotes





  1. ^ Matsui & Matsui 2000.


  2. ^ ab Straffin 1993.


  3. ^ Penrose 1946.


  4. ^ Felsenthal & Machover 1998, p. 5.


  5. ^ Banzhaf 1965.


  6. ^ Coleman 1971.


  7. ^ Varela & Prado-Dominguez 2012.


  8. ^ Gelman & Katz 2002.




Bibliography


.mw-parser-output .refbegin{font-size:90%;margin-bottom:0.5em}.mw-parser-output .refbegin-hanging-indents>ul{list-style-type:none;margin-left:0}.mw-parser-output .refbegin-hanging-indents>ul>li,.mw-parser-output .refbegin-hanging-indents>dl>dd{margin-left:0;padding-left:3.2em;text-indent:-3.2em;list-style:none}.mw-parser-output .refbegin-100{font-size:100%}



Banzhaf, John F. (1965). "Weighted Voting Doesn't Work: A Mathematical Analysis". Rutgers Law Review. 19 (2): 317–343. ISSN 0036-0465..mw-parser-output cite.citation{font-style:inherit}.mw-parser-output .citation q{quotes:"""""""'""'"}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-free a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/6/65/Lock-green.svg/9px-Lock-green.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-limited a,.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-registration a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/d/d6/Lock-gray-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-gray-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-subscription a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/a/aa/Lock-red-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-red-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration{color:#555}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription span,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration span{border-bottom:1px dotted;cursor:help}.mw-parser-output .cs1-ws-icon a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/4/4c/Wikisource-logo.svg/12px-Wikisource-logo.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output code.cs1-code{color:inherit;background:inherit;border:inherit;padding:inherit}.mw-parser-output .cs1-hidden-error{display:none;font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-visible-error{font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-maint{display:none;color:#33aa33;margin-left:0.3em}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration,.mw-parser-output .cs1-format{font-size:95%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-left,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-left{padding-left:0.2em}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-right,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-right{padding-right:0.2em}


Coleman, James S. (1971). "Control of Collectives and the Power of a Collectivity to Act". In Lieberman, Bernhardt. Social Choice. New York: Gordon and Breach. pp. 192–225.


Felsenthal, Dan S.; Machover, Moshé (1998). The Measurement of Voting Power Theory and Practice, Problems and Paradoxes. Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar.


 ———  ​ (2004). "A Priori Voting Power: What is it All About?". Political Studies Review. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. 2 (1): 1–23. doi:10.1111/j.1478-9299.2004.00001.x. ISSN 1478-9302.


Gelman, Andrew; Katz, Jonathan; Tuerlinckx, Francis (2002). "The Mathematics and Statistics of Voting Power". Statistical Science. 17 (4): 420–435. doi:10.1214/ss/1049993201. ISSN 0883-4237.


Lehrer, Ehud (1988). "An Axiomatization of the Banzhaf Value" (PDF). International Journal of Game Theory. 17 (2): 89–99. doi:10.1007/BF01254541. ISSN 0020-7276. Retrieved 30 August 2017.


Matsui, Tomomi; Matsui, Yasuko (2000). "A Survey of Algorithms for Calculating Power Indices of Weighted Majority Games" (PDF). Journal of the Operations Research Society of Japan. 43 (1): 71–86. ISSN 0453-4514. Retrieved 30 August 2017.


Penrose, Lionel (1946). "The Elementary Statistics of Majority Voting". Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Blackwell Publishing. 109 (1): 53–57. doi:10.2307/2981392. ISSN 0964-1998.


Straffin, Philip D. (1993). Game Theory and Strategy. New Mathematical Library. 36. Washington: Mathematical Association of America.


Varela, Diego; Prado-Dominguez, Javier (2012). "Negotiating the Lisbon Treaty: Redistribution, Efficiency and Power Indices". Czech Economic Review. 6 (2): 107–124. ISSN 1802-4696. Retrieved 30 August 2017.




External links








  • Online Power Index Calculator (by Tomomi Matsui)


  • Banzhaf Power Index Includes power index estimates for the 1990s U.S. Electoral College.


  • Voting Power Perl calculator for the Penrose index.


  • Computer Algorithms for Voting Power Analysis Web-based algorithms for voting power analysis


  • Power Index Calculator Computes various indices for (multiple) weighted voting games online. Includes some examples.


  • Computing Banzhaf power index and Shapley–Shubik power index with Python and R (by Frank Huettner)


  • Banzhaf Power Index at the Wolfram Demonstrations Project










這個網誌中的熱門文章

Xamarin.form Move up view when keyboard appear

Post-Redirect-Get with Spring WebFlux and Thymeleaf

Anylogic : not able to use stopDelay()